Hudson:
http://www.counterpunch.org/hudson04062009.html
April
6, 2009
Will the Debtors Fight Back?
The IMF Rules the
World
By MICHAEL HUDSON
Not much substantive news was
expected to come out of the G-20
meetings that ended on April 2 in
London – certainly no good news was
even suggested. Europe,
China and the United States had too deeply
distinct interests.
American diplomats wanted to lock foreign
countries into further
dependency on paper dollars. The rest of the
world sought a way to
avoid giving up real output and ownership of
their resources and
enterprises for yet more hot-potato dollars.
In
such cases one expects a parade of smiling faces and statements
of
mutual respect for each others’ position – so much
respect that they
have agreed to set up a “study group”
or two to kick the diplomatic
ball down the road.
The least
irrelevant news was not good at all: The attendees agreed
to
quadruple IMF funding to $1 trillion. Anything that bolsters
IMF
authority cannot be good for countries forced to submit to
its
austerity plans. They are designed to squeeze out more money
to pay
the world’s most predatory
creditors. So in practice this G-20
agreement means that
the world’s leading governments are responding to
today’s
financial crisis with “planned shrinkage” for debtors –
a 10 per cent cut in wage payments in hapless Latvia,
Hungary put on rations, and
permanent debt peonage for Iceland
for starters. This is
quite a contrast with the United States,
which is responding to the
downturn with a giant Keynesian deficit
spending program, despite its
glaringly unpayable $4 trillion debt
to foreign central banks.
So the
international financial system’s double standard remains
alive
and kicking – at least, kicking countries that
are down or are
falling. Debtor countries must borrow a trillion
from the IMF not to
revive their own faltering economies, not to
pursue counter-cyclical
policies to restore market demand (that is
only for creditor nations),
but to pass on the IMF “aid”
to the poisonous banks that have made the
irresponsible toxic
loans. (If these are toxic, who put in the toxin?
To claim that it
was all the “natural” workings of the marketplace is
to
say that free markets curdle and sicken. Is this what
is
happening?)
In Ukraine, a physical fight broke out in
Parliament when the Party of
Regions blocked an agreement with the
IMF calling for government
budget cutbacks. And rightly so! The
IMF’s operating philosophy is the
destructive (indeed,
toxic) belief that imposing a deeper depression
with more
unemployment will reduce wage levels and living standards by
enough
to pay debts already at unsustainable levels, thanks to
the
kleptocracy’s tax “avoidance” and capital
flight. The IMF
trillion-dollar bailout is actually for these
large international
banks, so that they will be able to take their
money and run. The
problem is all being blamed on labor. That is
the neo-Malthusian
spirit of today’s neoliberalism.
The
main beneficiaries of IMF lending to Latvia, for example, have
been
the Swedish banks that have spent the last decade funding
that
country’s real estate bubble while doing nothing to
help develop an
industrial potential. Latvia has paid for its
imports by exporting its
male labor of prime working age, acting
as a vehicle for Russian
capital flight – and borrowing
mortgage purchase-money in foreign
currency. To pay these debts
rather than default, Latvia will have to
lower wages in its public
sector by 10 per cent -- and this with an
economy already
depressed and that the government expects to shrink by
12 percent
this year!
To save the banks from losing on their toxic
mortgages, the IMF is
bailing them out, and directing the Latvian
government to squeeze
labor all the more – and to charge for
education rather than providing
it freely. The idea is for
families to take a lifetime of debt not
only to live inside rather
than on the sidewalk, but to get an
education. Alcoholism rates
are rising, as they did in Russia under
similar circumstances in
Yeltsin’s “Harvard Boys” kleptocracy
after
1996.
The insolvency problem of the
post-Soviet economies is not entirely
the IMF’s fault, to be
sure. The European Community deserves a great
deal of blame.
Instead of viewing the post-Soviet economies as wards
to be
brought up to speed with Western Europe, the last thing the EU
wanted
was to develop potential rivals. It wanted customers – not
only
for its exports, but most of all for its loans. The Baltic
States
passed into the Scandinavian sphere, while Austrian banks
carved out
financial spheres of influence in Hungary (and lost
their shirt on
real estate loans, much as the Habsburgs and
Rothschilds did in times
past). Iceland was neoliberalized,
largely in ripoffs organized by
German banks and British financial
sharpies.
In fact, Iceland ( where I’m
writing these lines) looks like a
controlled experiment –
a very cruel one – as to how deeply an economy
can be
“financialized” and how long its population will
submit
voluntarily to predatory financial behavior. If the attack
were
military, it would spur a more alert response. The
trick is to keep
the population from understanding the financial
dynamics at work and
the underlying fraudulent character of the
debts with which it has
been saddled – with the complicit
aid of its own local oligarchy.
In today’s world,
the easiest way to obtain wealth by old-fashioned
“primitive
accumulation” is by financial manipulation. This is the
essence
of the Washington Consensus that the G-20 support, using the
IMF
in its usual role as enforcer. The G-20’s announcement
continues
the U.S. Treasury and Federal Reserve bank bailout over
the past
half-year. In a nutshell, the solution to a debt crisis
is to be yet
more debt. If debtors can’t pay out of what
they are able to earn,
lend them enough to
keep current on their carrying charges.
Collateralize this
with
their property,
their public domain,
their political autonomy –
their democracy itself.
The aim is to keep the
debt overhead in place. This can be done
only by keeping the volume of
debts growing exponentially as they
accrue interest, which is added
onto the loan. This is the “magic
of compound interest.” It is what
turns
entire economies into Ponzi schemes (or Madoff schemes as
they
are now called).
This is “equilibrium”,
neoliberal style. In addition to paying
an
exorbitant basic interest rate, homeowners must pay a special
18 per
cent indexation charge on their debts to reflect the
inflation rate
(the consumer price index) so that creditors will
not lose the
purchasing power over consumer goods. Labor’s
wages are not indexed,
so defaults are spreading and the country
is being torn apart with
bankruptcy, causing the highest
unemployment rate since the Great
Depression. The IMF approves,
announcing that it can find no reason
why homeowners cannot bear
this burden!
Meanwhile, democracy is being torn apart by a
financial oligarchy,
whose interests have become increasingly
cosmopolitan, looking at the
economy as prey to be looted. A new
term is emerging: “codfish
republic” (known further
south as banana republics). Many of Iceland’s
billionaires
these days are choosing to join their Russian
counterparts living
in London – and the Russian gangsters are
reciprocating by
visiting Iceland even in the dead of winter,
ostensibly merely to
enjoy its warm volcanic Blue Lagoon, or so the
press is told.
The
alternative is for debtor countries to suffer the same kind
of
economic sanctions as Iran, Cuba and pre-invasion Iraq. Perhaps
soon
there will be enough such economies to establish a common
trading area
among themselves, possibly along with Venezuela,
Colombia and Brazil.
But as far as the G-20 is concerned, aid to
Iceland and “doing the
right thing” is simply a
bargaining chip in the international
diplomatic game. Russia
offered $4 billion aid to Iceland, but
retracted it –
presumably when Britain gave it a plum as a tradeoff.
The
IMF’s $1 trillion won’t help the post-Soviet and Third
World
debtor countries pay their foreign debts, especially their
real estate
mortgages denominated in foreign currency. This
practice has violated
the First Law of national fiscal prudence:
Only permit debts to be
taken on that are in
the same currency as the income that is expected
to be earned to
pay them off. If central bankers really sought to
protect
currency stability, they would insist on this rule. Instead,
they
act as shills for the international banks, as disloyal to the
actual
economic welfare of their countries as expatriate oligarchs.
If
you are going to recommend more of this consensus, then the only
way
to sell it is to do what British Prime Minister Gordon Brown did
at
the meetings: announce that “The Washington Consensus is dead.”
(He
might have saved matters by saying “deadly,” but
used the adjective
instead of the adverb.) But the G-20’s
IMF bailout belies this claim.
As Turkey was closing out its loan
last year, the IMF faced a world
with no customers. Nobody wanted
to submit to its destructive
“conditionalities,”
anti-labor policies designed to shrink the
domestic market in the
false assumption that this “frees” more output
for
export rather than being consumed at home. In reality, the effect
of
austerity is to discourage domestic investment, and hence
employment.
Economies submitting to the IMF’s “Washington
Consensus”
become more and more dependent on their foreign
creditors and
suppliers.
The United States and Britain
would never follow such
conditionalities. That is why the United
States has not permitted an
IMF advisory team to write up its
prescription for U.S. “stability.”
The Washington
Consensus is only for export. (“Do as we say, not as we
do.”)
Mr. Obama’s stimulus program is Keynesian, not an
austerity
plan, despite the fact that the United States is the
world’s largest
debtor.
Here’s why the
situation is unsustainable. What has enabled the
Baltics and other
post-Soviet countries to cover the foreign-exchange
costs of their
trade dependency and capital flight has been their real
estate
bubble. The neoliberal idea of financial
“equilibrium” has been
to watch “market forces”
shorten lifespans, demolish what industrial
potential they had,
increase emigration and disease, and run up an
enormous foreign
debt with no visible way of earning the money to pay
it off. This
real estate bubble credit was extractive and parasitic,
not
productive. Yet the World Bank applauds the Baltics as a
success
story, ranking them near the top of nations in terms of
“ease of doing
business.”
One practical fact
trumps all the junk economics at work from the IMF
and G-20: Debts
that can’t be paid, won’t be. Adam Smith observed in
The
Wealth of Nations that no government in history had ever repaid
its
national debt. Today, the same may be said of the public sector
as
well. This poses a problem of just how these debtor countries
are not
going to pay their foreign and domestic debts. How
will they frame and
politicize their non-payment?
Creditors
know that these debts can’t be paid. (I
say this as former
balance-of-payments analyst of Third World debt
for nearly fifty
years, from Chase Manhattan in the 1960s through
the United Nations
Institute for Training and Research [UNITAR] in
the 1970s, to Scudder
Stevens & Clark in 1990, where I started
the first Third World
sovereign debt fund.) From the
creditor’s vantage point, knowing that
the Great Neoliberal
Bubble is over, the trick is to deter debtor
countries from acting
to resolve its collapse in a way that benefits
themselves. The aim
is to take as much as possible – and to get the
IMF and
central banks to bail out the poisonous banks that have loaded
these
countries down with toxic debt. Grab what you can while the
grabbing
is good. And demand that debtors do what Latin American and
other
third World countries have been doing since the 1980s: sell off
their
public domain and public enterprises at distress prices. That
way,
the international banks not only will get paid, they will get
new
business lending to the buyers of the assets being privatized
– on the
usual highly debt-leveraged terms!
The
preferred tactic do [to] deter debtor
countries from acting in their
self-interest is to pound on the
old morality, “A debt is a debt, and
must be paid.”
That is what Herbert Hoover said of the Inter-Ally
debts owed by
Britain, France and other allies of the United States in
World War
I. These debts led to the Great Depression. “We loaned them
the
money, didn’t we?” he said curtly.
Let’s
look more closely at the moral argument. Living in New York, I
find
an excellent model in that state’s Law of
Fraudulent Conveyance.
Enacted when the state was still a
colony, it was enacted in response
British speculators making
loans to upstate farmers, and demanding
payment just before the
harvest was in, when the debtors could not
pay. The sharpies then
foreclosed, getting the land on the cheap. So
New York’s
Fraudulent Conveyance law responded by establishing the
legal
principle that if a creditor makes a loan
without having a clear
and reasonable understanding of how the
debtor can repay the money in
the normal course of doing business,
the loan is deemed to be
predatory and therefore null and
void.
Just like the post-Soviet economies, Iceland was
sold a neoliberal
bill of goods: a
self-destructive Junk Economics. Just how moral a
responsibility –
and perhaps even more important, how large a legal
liability
–should fall on the IMF and World Bank, the U.S. Treasury
and
Bank of England whose economies and banks benefited from this
toxic
Washington Consensus junk economics?
For me, the moral
principle is that no country should be subjected to
debt peonage.
That is the opposite of democratic self-determination,
after all –
and of Enlightenment moral philosophy that economic
policies
should encourage economic growth, not shrinkage. They should
promote
greater economic equality, not polarization between wealthy
creditors
and impoverished debtors.
At issue is just what a “free
market” is. It’s supposed to be one of
choice.
Indebted countries lose discretionary choice over their
economic
future. Their economic surplus is pledged abroad as
financial
tribute. Without the overhead costs of a military
occupation, they are
relinquishing their policy making from
democratically elected
political representatives to bureaucratic
financial managers, often
foreign – the new Central Planners
in today’s neoliberal world.
The
best they can do, knowing the game is over, is to hope that
the other
side doesn’t realize it – and to do
everything you can to confuse
debtor countries while extracting as
much as they can as fast as they
can.
Will the trick work?
Maybe not. While the G-20 meetings were taking
place, Korea
was refusing to let itself be victimized by the junk
derivatives
contracts that foreign banks sold. Korea is claiming that
bankers
have a fiduciary responsibility to their customers to
recommend
loans that help them, not strip them of money. There is
a
tacit understanding (one that the financial sector spends
millions of
dollars in public relations efforts to undermine) that
banking is a
public utility. It is supposed to be a handmaiden to
growth –
industrial and agricultural growth and
self-sufficiency – not
predatory, extractive and hence
anti-social. So Korean victims of junk
derivatives are suing the
banks. As New York Times commentator Floyd
Norris described last
week, the legal situation doesn’t look
good for
the international banks. The home court always has
an advantage, and
every nation is sovereign, able to pass whatever
laws it wants. (And
as America’s case abundantly
illustrates, judges need not be
unbiased.)
The post-Soviet
economies as well as Latin America must be watching
attentively
the path that Korea is clearing through international
courts. The
nightmare of international bankers is that these countries
may
bring the equivalent of a class action suit
against the
international diplomatic coercion mounted against
these countries to
lead them down the path of financial and
economic suicide. “The Seoul
Central District Court
justified its decision [to admit the lawsuit]
on the kind of logic
that would apply in the United States to a
lawsuit involving an
unsophisticated individual investor and a
fast-taking broker. The
court pointed to questions of whether the
contract was a suitable
investment for the company, and to whether the
risks were fully
disclosed. The judgment also referred to the legal
concept of
“changed circumstances,” concluding that the parties
had
expected the exchange rate to remain stable, that the change
in
circumstances was unforeseeable and that the losses would be
too great
for the company to bear.”
As a second cause
of action, Korea is claiming that the banks provided
creditor for
other financial institutions to bet against the very
contracts the
banks were selling Korea to “protect” its interests.
So
the banks knew that what they were
selling was a time bomb, and
therefore seem guilty of conflict
of interest. Banks claim that they
merely were selling
goods with no warranty to “informed individuals.”
But
the Korean parties in question were no more informed than
were
Iceland’s debtors. If a bank seeks to mislead and does
not provide
full disclosure, its victim cannot be said to be
“informed.” The
proper English word is misinformed
(viz. disinformation).
.
Speaking of disinformation, an
important issue concerns the extent to
which the big international
banks may have conspired with domestic
bankers and corporate
managers to loot their companies. This is what
corporate raiders
have done for their junk-bond holders since the high
tide of
Drexel Burnham and Michael Milken in the 1980s. This would
make
the banks partners in crime. There needs to be an investigation
of
the lending pattern that these banks engaged in – including
their
aid in organizing offshore money laundering and tax evasion
to their
customers. No wonder the IMF and British bankers are
demanding that
Iceland make up its mind in a hurry, and commit
itself to pay
astronomical debts without taking the time to ask
just how they are to
pay – and investigating the creditor
banks’ overall lending pattern!
Bearing the above in
mind, I suppose I can tell Icelandic politicians
that I have good
news regarding the fate of their country’s foreign
and
domestic debt: No nation ever has paid its debts. As I noted
above,
this means that the real question is not whether or not they
will
be paid, but how not to pay these debts.
How will the game play
out – in the political sphere, in
popular ideology, and in the courts
at home and abroad?
The
question is whether Iceland will let bankruptcy tear apart
its
economy slowly, transferring property from debtors to
creditors, from
Icelandic citizens to foreigners, and from the
public domain and
national taxing power to the international
financial class. Or, will
Iceland see where the inherent
mathematics of debt are leading, and
draw the line? At
what point will it say “We won’t pay. These debts
are
immoral, uneconomic and anti-democratic.” Do they want
to continue
the fight by Enlightenment and Progressive Era social
democracy, or
the alternative – a lapse back into neofeudal
debt peonage?
This is the choice must be made. And it is
largely a question of
timing. That’s what the financial
sector plays for – time enough to
transfer as much property
as it can into the hands of the banks and
other investors. That’s
what the IMF advises debtor countries to do –
except
of course for the United States as largest debtor of all.
This
is the underlying lawless character of today’s
post-bubble debts.
Michael Hudson is a former Wall Street
economist. A Distinguished
Research Professor at University of
Missouri, Kansas City (UMKC), he
is the author of many books,
including Super Imperialism: The Economic
Strategy of American
Empire (new ed., Pluto Press, 2002) He can be
reached at
mh@michael-hudson.com